This article, written by 30 economics faculty of the University of the Philippines published in PDI (7/28/2012), "is an updated and abridged
version of an earlier paper first issued in August 2008 and reissued in
February 2011. It also partly derives from an older paper titled “Population
and Poverty: the Real Score” [December 2004]." The reference to former President Gloria Macapagal-Arroyo's stand on the RH Bill provides a historical input regarding the nuances in the discourse of RH Bill issues and concerns.
POPULATION, POVERTY, POLITICS AND RH BILL
CHILDREN on NIA Road in Quezon City. JOAN BONDOC |
That
it continues to be debated heatedly in our country merely testifies to the lack
of progress in policy and action. The Catholic Church hierarchy has maintained
its traditional stance against modern family planning (FP) methods, particularly
modern (also referred to as “artificial”) contraceptives.
On
the other hand, the State acknowledges the difficulties posed for development
by rapid population growth, especially among the poorest Filipinos. But it has
been immobilized from effectively addressing the issue by the Catholic
hierarchy’s hard-line position, as well as the tendency of some politicians to
cater to the demands of well-organized and impassioned single-issue groups for
the sake of expediency.
Caught
between a hard Church and a soft State are the overwhelming majority of
Filipinos who affirm the importance of helping women and couples control the
size of their families and the responsibility of the government to provide
budgetary support for modern FP services.
Renewed
impetus to the debate has been given by the public and political interest in
the decade-and-a-half old bill on “Responsible Parenthood, Reproductive Health,
and Population and Development” (RH bill, for short). Unfortunately, serious
discussion has been hampered by the lack of reliable information and the
proclivity of some parties in the debate to use epithets that label the bill as
“proabortion,” “antilife” and “immoral.”
There
were a few aspects of the bill to which some groups have expressed objections,
which the latest version has already addressed. In any case, the main thrust of
the bill—“enabl(ing) couples and individuals to decide freely and responsibly
the number and spacing of their children and to have the information and means
to carry out their decisions”—is something we strongly and unequivocally
support. In what follows, we explain why.
Real score
The experience from across Asia
indicates that population policy cum government-funded FP program has been a
critical complement to sound economic policy and poverty reduction. Moreover,
the weaker the state’s ability to tax and mobilize resources (including
spending on the right priorities) is, the greater the negative impact on
economic development of a rapidly growing population, which in every developing
country is largely accounted for by the least educated and poorest segments of
the population.
Owing
to the lack of a clear population policy (RH/FP programs) besides just modest
economic growth since the 1970s, our country sadly has fallen well behind its
original Asean neighbors (Thailand, Malaysia and Indonesia) in terms of both
demographic and economic indicators. (See Table 1.)
Sadder still is the prospect that unless
the RH (or responsible parenthood) bill is passed in Congress and swiftly
implemented, our country will likely be overtaken even by its latecomer Asean
neighbors (Vietnam, Cambodia, Laos and Myanmar) in a few years time.
At the micro level, large family size is
closely associated with poverty incidence, as consistently borne out by
household survey data over time. In short, poor families are heavily burdened
when they end up with more children than they want.
Official data from the Family
Income and Expenditures Survey (FIES) since 1985 have unambiguously shown that
poverty incidence is lower for families with fewer children but rises
consistently with the number of children. (See Table 2.) Among families with
one child only 2.9 percent are poor compared with households having nine or
more children where 46.4 percent are destitute (FIES 2009).
Moreover, larger families make smaller
investment in human capital per child—investment that is crucial to breaking
the vicious chain of intergenerational poverty. Average annual spending on
education per student falls from P8,212 for a one-child family to P2,474 for a
family with nine or more children, and average health spending per capita drops
correspondingly from P3,389 to P582 (FIES 2006 and Labor Force Survey 2007).
The poor prefer smaller families, except
that they are unable to achieve their preference. The poorer the household, the
higher the “unwanted” number of children: Table 3 shows that total fertility
rate (TFR) among the poorest has been consistently higher by around two than
“wanted” number of children; by contrast, among the richer families there is
virtually no difference between actual TFR and “wanted” numbers.
On the average, among the poorest 10
percent of women of reproductive age, 44 percent of pregnancies are unwanted
[Family Planning Survey (FPS) 2006]. Overall, 54 percent of all pregnancies are
unintended [Guttmacher Institute and UP Population Institute (GI and UPPI),
“Meeting Women’s Contraceptive Needs in the Philippines,” 2009]. Unwanted
births represent a considerable unmet need for FP services. Among the poorest
families, 22 percent of married women of reproductive age express a desire to
avoid pregnancies but are still not using any family planning method (FPS
2006).
Contraceptive use remains extremely low
among poor couples because they lack information and access. For instance,
among the poorest 20 percent of women, over half do not use any method of
family planning whatsoever, while less than a third use modern methods (FPS
2006). Among the poorest women, who want to avoid pregnancy, at least 41
percent are unable to practice any method of contraception.
Lack of access to contraception has
important health implications. The maternal mortality rate (MMR), already high
at 162 per 100,000 live births [Family Health Survey (FHS) 2006], has risen
further to 221 (FHS 2011) and, hence, it is highly unlikely to meet the Millennium
Development Goal of 52 by 2015. Having too many and too closely spaced children
raises the risk of illness and premature deaths (for mother and child alike).
From 11 women dying daily owing to
pregnancy and childbirth-related causes based on the 2006 MMR, this number had
risen to at least 15 maternal deaths each day as of 2011. Moreover, many
unwanted pregnancies result in induced and illegal abortions, numbering 560,000
annually as of 2008 (GI and UPPI 209).
The health risks associated with mistimed
and unwanted pregnancies are higher for adolescent mothers, as they are more
likely to have childbirth-related complications. Almost 25 percent of
uneducated teenagers begin childbearing compared with only 3 percent of those
who have attended college or higher. The pregnancy rate among teen-aged girls
rose from 39 per 1,000 women in 2006 to 54 more recently (FHS 2011).
There are unintended social costs
(negative externalities) arising from mistimed and unplanned pregnancies.
Parents, who are able to space their children and achieve their desired number,
are also more likely to bear the full cost of raising and educating them.
By contrast, poor families having more
children than desired are constrained to rely on public education and health
services and other publicly provided goods and services. In short, in a
situation where government is already hard-pressed in financing even the most
basic items of public spending, having no national population policy is
tantamount to burying one’s head in the sand.
Moreover, women who have children sooner
than planned are rarely in the best of health during pregnancy and are more
likely to seek medical treatment. And poor women typically utilize public
health care facilities. Public education and health facilities are already
congested and decongesting them would entail increased taxation.
Providing services for planning and
spacing pregnancies is one way of alleviating the tax burden. Teen pregnancies
also impose a social cost. Since teen mothers are more likely to drop out of
school, they are also less able to internalize the cost of rearing their
children and more likely to shift this burden to the government.
Ensuring access to the full range of
modern FP methods cum appropriate information raises the success rate of achieving
the desired family size. Limiting FP options to “natural family planning (NFP)
methods only” fails to address the private and social costs of mistimed and
unwanted pregnancies. NFP methods typically have a 24-percent failure rate—meaning that if 100 women adopt NFP, 24 of them would typically become
pregnant in a year (Ponzetti, J.J. and Hoefler S. “Natural family planning: A
review and assessment,” Family and Community Health (1988) 11 (2): 36-48).
The data highlight the importance
of full information and access to the whole range of modern methods, rather
than NFP only. Figure 1 shows a close association between the reduction in the
average number of children a woman bears, use of modern methods, and, to some
extent, lower utilization of traditional methods. The RH bill addresses both
private and social costs of uninformed, unplanned and unprotected reproductive
health behavior.
All told, RH and FP programs offer a
win-win solution. They lift the well-being of individual women and children,
and benefit the economy and the environment as well.
Distortions
The current debate on the population issue
has become unnecessarily muddled by conceptual and factual distortions. Some
groups, including the Catholic Bishops’ Conference of the Philippines and other
“prolife” groups, vehemently oppose the RH bill because they claim that it is
proabortion and is antilife.
A studious reading of the bill, however,
shows that these are clearly erroneous claims. In the first place, there is an
obvious definitional and scientific difference between contraception, which
occurs before conception, and abortion, which occurs after.
In the second place, the bill’s main
thrust is to provide full information on, access to and choice from among the
whole range of traditional, modern, and “natural” family planning methods for
contraception. The bill is, in fact, unequivocally and explicitly against
abortion—thus, “abortion shall remain penalized under the Revised Penal Code
and relevant jurisprudence.”
Some objectors to the RH bill have further
argued that the bill will only lead to promiscuity, the breakup of families,
decay of moral values and hedonism. But this is pure ideological conjecture—an
assertion sans logic and empirical basis. Gratis asseritur, gratis negatur.
Sadly, the previous administration also
contributed to the confusion. Former President Gloria Macapagal-Arroyo asserted
at the General Assembly of the United Nations in its 60th session on Sept. 15,
2005 that NFP technology was found “effective compared to artificial
contraceptives” by the World Health Organization (WHO).
She added that: “the Population Council of
New York has found that artificial contraception contributes only 2.0 percent
to the decline of birth rates while the combination of improving the economic
condition of the family, urbanization and breast-feeding contributes 98
percent.” When asked for their reactions, however, both the WHO and the
Population Council categorically disavowed the former President’s statements.
More misinformation was contained in the
former President’s Sona (July 28, 2008). She asserted that her policy of NFP
combined with female education reduced population growth to 2.04 percent during
her administration compared with 2.36 percent when “artificial” birth control
techniques were pushed. At best, the former President’s statement was
disingenuous, since it is well-known that more educated females are more likely
to use modern (“artificial”) contraceptive methods.
On the other hand, how could the use of
“modern NFP” have contributed to the fall in population growth when its use
rate among married women of reproductive age (15-49) actually dropped from 0.5
percent to 0.3 percent in 2001-2006? By contrast, their use of modern (“artificial”)
contraceptives rose from 33 percent to 36 percent during the same period. This
actually implies that it was modern (“artificial”) contraceptive use that rose
as women became more educated, and thus was more likely to be associated with
the decline in the population growth rate.
Conclusion
Debate is always healthy: religious and
other groups are perfectly free to espouse their own views and opinions. The
line must be drawn, however, at that point where deliberate efforts are made to
misinform and distort the true and well-meaning provisions of the RH bill.
An unambiguous and consistent national
population policy is long overdue in our country. It is an integral part of
development and poverty reduction strategy. Once passed, the RH bill can be a
good instrument of national policy for population and development.
Espousing “natural family planning only”
is a position inconsistent with the spirit and letter of the bill and reflects
a lack of seriousness in pursuing long-term economic development and poverty
reduction.
It is in this spirit of debate that we
express our own opinion. We say—based on serious evidence—that the RH bill is
propoor and authentically prolife and profamily.
We, therefore, strongly support the RH
bill and urge the national leadership to be fully and unequivocally behind it.
It is time the President declared the RH bill urgent.
(The UP economists are Ernesto M.
Pernia, Stella Alabastro-Quimbo, Maria Joy V. Abrenica, Ruperto P. Alonzo,
Agustin L. Arcenas, Arsenio M. Balisacan, Dante B. Canlas, Joseph J. Capuno,
Ramon L. Clarete, Rolando A. Danao, Emmanuel S. de Dios, Aleli de la Paz-Kraft,
Benjamin E. Diokno, Geoffrey M. Ducanes, Marina B. Durano, Emmanuel F.
Esguerra, Raul V. Fabella, Teresa J. Ho, Dennis Claire S. Mapa, Felipe M.
Medalla, Maria Nimfa F. Mendoza, Solita C. Monsod, Toby Melissa C. Monsod,
Fidelina Natividad-Carlos, Aniceto C. Orbeta, Cayetano W. Paderanga, Majah-Leah
V. Ravago, Gerardo P. Sicat, Orville C. Solon and Edita A. Tan.
The authors represent nearly all
members of the UP School of Economics faculty. The opinions expressed in this
paper, however, reflect solely the views of the authors and not the official
position of the UP School of Economics. The paper is an updated and abridged
version of an earlier paper first issued in August 2008 and reissued in
February 2011. It also partly derives from an older paper titled “Population
and Poverty: the Real Score” [December 2004], prepared largely by the same
authors.)
No comments:
Post a Comment